Monday, December 30, 2013
My letter to the Philadelphia Inquirer re: Mark Zandi ignores reality
Re: Good Times Ahead, by Mark Zandi
Dear Sirs:
According to Mark Zandi, chief economist for Moody's Analytics, the only possible bump in the inevitable road to economic recovery in 2014 is another threatened government shutdown. Mr. Zandi, like all good Keynesians, sees increased spending by consumers as the road to recovery. And consumers are more likely to spend if the spigot of federal dollars, created out of thin air when the Fed "purchases" government's trillion dollar per year debt, remains wide open. He is unconcerned about the risk of hyperinflation or the dislocations caused to the capital structure of production as businesses are enticed by low, manipulated interest rates to begin expansions for which there are insufficient resources for profitable completion. Mr. Zandi has no theory of economics more sophisticated than that of a child who demands a bigger allowance from his father. Like a child he does not care where the money comes from or how it is spent. For Mr. Zandi, spending alone is the key and savers are completely unnecessary. How anyone can believe this nonsense is beyond me.
Friday, December 27, 2013
The Collapse of the Irish Housing Boom
Re: Irish Try to Eradicate Ghosts of a Housing Crash
Lord Keynes famously said that paying people to dig holes and fill them back up was necessary for recovery. His disciple Paul Krugman wants Martians to attack earth so that we can spur the economy via war spending.
Read the above NY Times report, if you have a strong enough stomach. Keynes would have applauded the Irish housing boom, and von Mises would have explained that such malinvestment leads to bankruptcy and poverty. I would add that it leads to despair, as the wealth, hopes, and dreams of hard working people are shattered.
Monday, December 16, 2013
A Plan to Arrive at 100% Reserves on Bank Demand Deposits
Introduction
This paper deals with the steps that are required to cover bank demand
deposits 100% by reserves. We will deal
with ending the ability of the banking system to pyramid reserves into new
money, created out of thin air, and will show the steps necessary for the
banking system to transition from a fractional reserve system to 100% reserves
without creating new reserves and without shrinking the money supply. The paper will discuss the feasibility and
the method to successfully transition to this new banking structure. Monetary
expansion via the banking side would end, as would inflation and the boom/bust
business cycle. (See note #1)
Summary
of expected outcomes
Banking services would be divided into two separate businesses as
described in chapters six and seven of Murray N. Rothbard's The Mystery of Banking. Bank demand deposits (checking accounts) would
be backed 100% by reserves, housed in new Deposit Banks that provide payment
services only. Bank savings and time
deposits would be backed by loans and securities, housed in new Loan Banks. A Deposit Bank customer who wishes to earn an
interest return on his excess demand funds opens an account at the Loan
Bank. He transfers ownership of his excess
demand funds to the loan banker, who further transfers ownership of the demand
money to his borrowing customer. In
other words, the original demand account holder "lends" his money to
the loan banker, who further lends it to his (the loan banker's) customer. The loan banker acts as a financial
intermediary, finding good credits and managing them in order to pay interest
to his depositors (who actually are lenders to the Loan Bank). He must earn enough from the loans he finds
to pay interest to his depositors, fund his lending operation, and set aside a
reserve for bad debt. Notice that no new money is created anywhere
in this process. The Loan Bank's borrower takes temporary
possession of the money originally in the Deposit Bank. The possessor of the same money has changed
temporarily, but no new money was created.
This paper will discuss the feasibility and method to successfully
transition to this new banking structure.
Enough
cash to cover demand accounts but not savings and time accounts
Here is the aggregate balance sheet (trillions of dollars) for all US
banks as of November 2013 per Federal Reserve Data:
Current Banking System
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|||
Cash Assets
|
$2.630
|
|
||
Loans
|
$7.378
|
|
||
Securities
|
$2.698
|
|
||
Total Loans & Securities
|
$10.076
|
|
||
Other Assets
|
$1.275
|
|
||
Total Assets
|
$13.981
|
|||
|
|
|||
|
|
|||
Demand Deposits
|
$1.479
|
|
||
Non-demand Deposit
|
$8.267
|
|
||
Total Deposits
|
$9.746
|
|
||
Borrowings
|
$1.570
|
|
||
Other Liabilities
|
$1.137
|
|
||
Total Liabilities
|
$12.453
|
|
||
Capital
|
$1.528
|
|
||
Total Liabilities & Capital
|
|
|
|
$13.981
|
Morphing
the current banking system into a Rothbardian banking system
But is this really a problem?
The banks do have loans and securities of $10.076 trillion, well in
excess of the amount needed to secure their savings and time deposits in the
Loan Bank. Would not these depositors prefer
to keep their funds invested rather than decide to "cash out" their
savings and time deposits, accept the penalties, and place all or most of their
money in the Deposit Bank where they not only would not receive interest but
would pay fees to boot? Let's take a
look at how the new Deposit and Loan Banks might be constructed after the split
and what might entice savings and time depositors to keep their money in a new
Loan Bank. Here is what the new aggregated
Deposit Bank and Loan Bank would look like:
Deposit Bank
|
||||
Cash Assets
|
$1.479
|
|||
Loans
|
||||
Securities
|
||||
Total Loans & Securities
|
||||
Other Assets
|
$0.638
|
|||
Total Assets
|
$2.117
|
|||
Demand Deposits
|
$1.479
|
|||
Non-demand Deposit
|
$0.000
|
|||
Total Deposits
|
$1.479
|
|||
Borrowings
|
$0.000
|
|||
Other Liabilities
|
$0.000
|
|||
Total Liabilities
|
$1.479
|
|||
Capital
|
$0.638
|
|||
Total Liabilities & Capital
|
$2.117
|
Loan Bank
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|||
Cash Assets
|
$1.151
|
|
||
Loans
|
$7.378
|
|
||
Securities
|
$2.698
|
|
||
Total Loans & Securities
|
$10.076
|
|
||
Other Assets
|
$0.638
|
|
||
Total Assets
|
$11.865
|
|||
|
|
|||
|
|
|||
Demand Deposits
|
$0.000
|
|
||
Non-demand Deposit
|
$8.267
|
|
||
Total Deposits
|
$8.267
|
|
||
Borrowings
|
$1.570
|
|
||
Other Liabilities
|
$1.137
|
|
||
Total Liabilities
|
$10.974
|
|
||
Capital
|
$0.891
|
|
||
Total Liabilities & Capital
|
|
|
|
$11.865
|
Here's how I divided the
assets, liabilities, and capital:
1. I moved all of the demand deposits into
the Deposit Bank and all of the non-demand deposits into the Loan Bank.
2. I gave the Deposit Bank enough of the cash assets to cover the demand deposits 100%. I gave the rest to the Loan Bank.
2. I gave the Deposit Bank enough of the cash assets to cover the demand deposits 100%. I gave the rest to the Loan Bank.
3. I gave the
Deposit Bank the loans, securities, and the other half of the Other Assets.
4. I divided the Other Assets equally between the two banks, assume these to be mostly fixed assets and office equipment.
5. I gave the Deposit Bank enough Capital to balance its Liability side with its Asset side. I gave the rest to the Loan Bank.
5. I gave the Loan Bank all the Borrowings and all the Other Liabilities.
4. I divided the Other Assets equally between the two banks, assume these to be mostly fixed assets and office equipment.
5. I gave the Deposit Bank enough Capital to balance its Liability side with its Asset side. I gave the rest to the Loan Bank.
5. I gave the Loan Bank all the Borrowings and all the Other Liabilities.
Here are the results:
1. The capital ratio of the Deposit Bank is 30.1%; the capital ratio of the Loan Bank is 7.5%.
2. The Loan Bank's liabilities of $10.974 are secured by cash, loans, and securities of $11.227.
3 The Loan Bank has cash equal to 11.7% of its loans and borrowings, meaning that almost 12% of the non-demand depositors would have to ask for their money before the Loan Bank would be forced to sell some of its securities.
4. The Loan
bank has securities equal to another 24.6% of its non-demand deposits, so, in
total the Loan Bank has cash and securities equal to 35.1% of its non-demand
deposits to pay for deposit withdrawals.
5. For individual
Loan Banks that nonetheless find themselves short of cash and securities, the
only answer is to sell their loans in the market at whatever discount is
required to raise the funds necessary to honor their current deposit contracts. Now the issue becomes one of simple market
forces. How much of a discount will
these banks be forced to accept?
If customers wish to hold more
demand accounts, secured by 100% fiat money, they will pay for the privilege in
the form of fees at the new Deposit Bank, because the Deposit Bank will not be
allowed to invest the cash, as is currently allowed by fractional reserve
banking laws. Banks who run out of excess
reserves to back their redeemed savings and time deposits will be forced to
sell some of their loans to banks with excess reserves. They may be forced to offer discounted prices
to these investors, which means the purchasers, presumably the new Loan Banks,
will receive a higher return. This will
give a great incentive for current savings and time deposit customers to keep
their deposits in a new Loan Bank rather than hold all their money in the form
of demand deposits in a new Deposit Bank and pay fees for the privilege.
Individual banks that cannot
raise enough cash to honor all of its demand deposits must declare bankruptcy. Their depositors will be paid out of the FDIC
insurance fund. This is a one-time
occurrence, for after the banking system has been split into Deposit Banks and
Loan Banks, the FDIC will be dissolved.
Regardless of whether banks make a profit or loss on securing their
demand accounts 100% by cash, the accounting equation is fairly
straightforward: the Deposit Banks
credit their loan accounts on the asset side and debit their savings and time deposits
accounts on the liability side to the extent required so that the Deposit Bank
holds only demand accounts, all of which are backed 100% by cash. The loans will be debited to the asset side
of the Loan Bank, securing the savings and time deposit liabilities that were
credited to the liability side.
The
look of the new Loan Banks
We can assume that some investors will want packages of highly rated
loans and will be willing to accept a lower return for a more secure
investment. At the other end of the
market will be packages of riskier loans offering higher rates of return as
compensation for the increased risk. We
can expect great market diversity in the quality of loans within the same Loan
Bank and among the many new Loan Banks.
For example, a new Loan Bank may offer several loan funds of differing
risks and returns, or there may be many Loan Banks that specialize in only one
or a few loan funds of the same kind of risk, ranging from silk stocking funds
that pay low returns to high flyer funds that pay higher returns. The market will determine the true value of
the funds. We should expect a great deal
of market volatility at first, as the banking market reshapes itself.
Conclusion
The banking system has more than enough reserves to back its demand
deposits 100%. Even assuming that some
current savings and time depositors would decide to accept deposit contract
penalties and move their funds to one of the new Deposit Banks, there seem to
be enough excess reserves to cover anticipated redemptions of this kind. If not, those banks with insufficient
reserves would be forced to sell loans at whatever rate the market requires to
those banks with excess reserves. In the
end, all demand deposits held in the new Deposit Banks would be backed 100% by
cash. Savings and time deposits held in
the new Loan Banks would be backed by some cash, some securities, but mostly
loans. These savings and time deposits
would not be insured; the only insurance available to depositors would be the
bankers' capital accounts and their reputations for finding good loans. The marketplace of Loan Banks would be very
diverse, composed at one end by long standing, very safe banks with lots of
capital, silk stocking loans, and offering low savings rates. At the other end of the market would be start
up banks with higher risk loans, less capital, and offering higher deposit
rates. The age of vanilla banking would
be over as well as the age of moral hazard created by government deposit
guarantees.
Assuming that the Fed is not allowed to increase reserves ex nihilo, this
process of establishing the new Deposit Banks and new Loan Banks will result in
a fixed money supply of notes, coins, and reserve balances at the Fed that can
be converted into cash at any time. Today
we call this the "monetary base".
The banks always must maintain reserves in an amount not less than their
demand account balances. Their reserves
must be some mix of cash in their vaults plus balances at the Fed that can be
converted to cash.
At this point the banking system will no longer be able to create money
out of thin air via the lending process, which it was able to do under the
fractional reserve banking system. The banking
side of the US monetary system will be placed on a sound, non-inflationary
basis and this source of periodic boom/bust business cycles will be eliminated.
Note #1:
At this point we are discussing fiat money reserves and, as such, it is
still possible for the Fed to manufacture reserves out of thin air by several
means. Although preventing the further
expansion of fiat reserves is vitally important and many may consider it to be
the logical first step to monetary reform, limiting the Fed's power to do this
is the subject of another paper.
Note #2:
Cash assets in
commercial banks (cash and reserves held at the Fed): $2.630 Trillion
Bank loans: $7.337 Trillion
Bank
securities: $2.698
Trillion
Bank loans and
securities: $10.076 Trillion
Demand accounts in
banks: $1.479 Trillion
Non-demand
accounts in banks: $8.317 Trillion
Total deposits in
banks: $9.796 Trillion
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)