Our monetary czars lecture us to be unconcerned about their
unprecedented expansions in base money and the money supply, since there has
been little sign of inflation in the economy.
For the purposes of this essay, we will assume that there has been no
inflation, although John Williams at www.shadowstats.com and anyone who tries
to make ends meet on the same money income will tell you a different
story. Our purpose is to explain the
theory behind the price level and how theory can explain the so-called
miracle/mystery of an increase in monetary aggregates with little or no
inflation.
There is no miracle or mystery as to why prices have not gone
significantly higher. Our monetary
authorities have not found the magic formula that allows the government to
engage in noninflationary spending sprees, funded neither by an increase in
taxes nor an increase in interest rates.
Our monetary masters remind me of the story of the man who jumps off the
Empire State Building. As he is passing
a floor on the way down, an office worker leans out a window and asks him how
he's doing. He replies: so far, so good!
What
determines the price level
On page 505 of his magnum opus, Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics, George Reisman defines the price level as a formula: P = Dc/Sc. P is the price level. The numerator Dc represents demand for goods as manifested in a definite total expenditure of money. The denominator Sc represents the supply of goods as manifested in a definite total quantity of goods produced and sold. Notice the importance not of the total supply of money but of that portion of the supply actually spent. A Scrooge McDuck swimming in his supply of money in his basement does not affect the price level until he actually spends some of his money. Similarly, if the money supply increases but remains
unspent, it will have no effect on the price level. In fact, if the demand to hold money exceeds
the growth of the money supply, prices actually will fall. Likewise, notice the importance of the supply
of goods as that portion of production actually sold. For example, inventory accumulation does not
affect the price level. The goods must
be both offered on the market and sold at some market clearing price for them
to affect the price level.
Therefore, two events, or a combination thereof, can cause prices
to rise--an increase in sales expressed in money terms, independent of whether
or not the supply of money has increased, or a decrease in supply sold on the
market, even if increased production goes into inventory accumulation. The opposite of these two events, of course,
will cause prices to fall.
We easily see from this simple yet powerful explanation that a
falling price level need not be of concern, if it is the result of an increase
in the supply of goods offered on the market.
As John Stuart Mill explained over two hundred years ago, the purpose of
production is consumption. Goods are
produced to satisfy human wants. The
Keynesian view that digging holes and filling them up again adds to the general
welfare of an economy is nonsense. Jean
Baptist Say explained that increased production becomes the means by which
increased sales are realized. Again, man
produces for the purpose of consumption, and his production becomes the means
by which he consumes via market exchange expressed in money terms. Digging and refilling holes does not represent
anything that would be valued on the market.
Neither would printing money and giving it to welfare recipients to
spend.
OK, but what would cause an increase in the demand to hold money
that would suppress the price level? And
is this increase in money demand something that we can rely upon to hold down
the price level forever?
Mises'
Three Phases of Inflation that Lead to Money Destruction
Ludwig von Mises explained that there are three phases to
monetary destruction. Murray N. Rothbard summarizes Mises' explanation in
his Mystery of Banking,
Chapter V (The Demand for Money), pages
68 through 72.
In phase one the monetary authorities inflate the currency, but
the public expects that prices will not rise or may actually fall, so they
withhold their spending, which is the same thing as saying that they increase
their demand to hold money. Prices may actually drop during this
period of monetary inflation, which seems paradoxical but actually is explained
by proper theory. The demand to hold money rises faster than the supply
printed by the monetary authorities. The people believe that whatever
crisis causes an increase in money will end and prices will fall to pre-crisis
levels or even lower. They are long
accustomed to lower prices or even a gently falling price level. Therefore, their firmly held belief in lower
prices becomes self-fulfilling, at least for awhile, because their increase in
demand to hold money brings about this very situation.
Phase one may last a long time, but eventually the demand to hold
money abates and prices start to rise, gently at first but more robustly as
time progresses. In this second phase
the people come to believe that prices are not going to fall and that they actually
will continue to rise. Therefore, they
begin spending more to purchase goods before the inevitable increase in
prices. In this phase, even if the monetary authorities shrink the
money supply, prices still can rise, because the people's demand to hold
money is falling too fast. Again, the people's belief that prices will
continue to rise becomes self-fulfilling.
Price increases in phase two come faster and faster, as more and more
people accelerate their spending to thwart the falling purchasing power of
their money.
Phase two morphs into phase three, when people lose all confidence
in the future purchasing power of their money and demand to hold money goes to
zero. In this final phase the monetary
authorities are unsuccessful in stopping the loss of monetary confidence even
if they take drastic action to curb monetary inflation. People wish to
exchange their money for any vendible commodity. The panic feeds on itself. This is what Mises calls the
"crackup boom", because there is a flurry of buying as everyone tries
to exchange his money for whatever he can.
The Cantillon Effect and Boom/Bust
Business Cycle
Not only do our monetary masters fail to understand the real
danger of monetary destruction that they have unleashed with their zero
interest rate and quantitative easing policies, they do not understand the true
nature of money as part and parcel of the market. For example, they fail to understand that
money is not neutral. Its expansion does
not fall upon the economy equally, perhaps raising the price level but not
disturbing its underlying structure. In
his eighteenth century book, An Essay on Economic Theory,
Richard Cantillon first observed that money enters the economy in certain
places, enriching the early receivers of new money at the expense of later
receivers. Money expansion transfers
wealth within society, benefiting the politically connected and harming the
true engines of progress, the savers. This
is the Cantillon Effect of the non-neutrality of money. In his first great book, The Theory of Money and Credit, Ludwig
von Mises went even further and corrected a major deficiency of the classical
economists by integrating money into general economic theory that governs all
economic processes. For example, money
is just as much subject to the law of diminishing marginal utility as all other
goods and services. Our monetary masters
admit as much when they muse that more recent quantitative easing measures have
had less effect on their favored monetary metrics than earlier ones. What they do not understand is that the
economy was not helped by increases in money.
Quite the contrary.
At the conclusion of The Theory
of Money and Credit, Mises introduced another great contribution to
economic theory: that bank credit expansion is the source of the boom/bust
business cycle. Money and GDP aggregates
fail to identify the capital destruction set in motion by monetary
interventions. GDP may indeed increase
but only due only to the Keynesian fascination with monetary aggregates. The capital structure of production is set in
disequilibrium, sending too much capital to the earlier, long term stages of
production which eventually cannot be completed due to the fact that there
never were enough resources in the economy for their profitable
completion. Mises termed such
misallocation "malinvestment".
No one can predict when people will begin to lose confidence in
the purchasing power of the dollar. Each new dollar that the Fed creates
is like one more strand of straw laid on a mountain of straw. The real question is "Is this next
strand of straw going to be the one that breaks the camel's back?"
I love the strand of straw image.
ReplyDelete